Great Expectations for 2004: A year of optimism?
07/05/2004 - Speeches
Speech by Mr. Panayotis Thomopoulos,
Deputy Governor of the Bank of Greece
"Great Expectations for 2004: A year of optimism?
The Economic Outlook"
at the Economist Conference (5-7/5/04)
on Friday 7th of May 2004, at Divani Apollon Palace
I am glad that I can answer the question posed for this
session in the affirmative. Yes, 2004 is a year of optimism, and, provided that
appropriate policies are introduced, optimism should continue in 2005 as well.
However, since we are living in a rapidly changing world, single global periodic
shocks of various origins are, unfortunately, becoming a routine and since
macroeconomic equilibria and "harmonious" growth are mirages, the
answer cannot be a simple Yes. It is more propitious to say yes, but. Ôhe
but refers to two factors. First, there are growing divergences in economic
performance across the globe, with the result that the dividends of the recovery
are not being evenly spread among the major regions of the world. Although the
differences in economic performance can be attributed mainly to domestic factors,
the policies of certain economic powers are also contributing to the sub-optimal
performance of other regions. Second, looking further ahead, it is appropriate
to sound a warning that in an uncertain international environment governments,
central banks and financial supervisors as well as the private sector should not
take for granted the recent good performance. Rather they should take decisive
action to prolong this recovery and avoid the realization of downside risks.
After three miserable years of below par growth, it is now
clear that the world economy has entered a period of improving economic
performance. World output is expected to increase by 4.6 percent this year, 50%
faster than in the previous two years, while world trade, which practically
stagnated in 2001 and 2002, will increase by nearly 8 percent this year.
Although this performance falls short of the heady days of the late 1990s, it is
a significant improvement over the recent past.
This rebound now covers practically the whole world, albeit
to varying degrees, with most major countries benefiting from accelerating
growth. However again the rate of growth in certain regions will continue to be
considerably below their potential rate. Even Japan is now looking forward to a
durable recovery in part as a result of the decrease in banks' contingent
liabilities and of strong export demand, especially from China. Many Latin
American countries have turned the page of distress and have been recording fast,
though still fragile, growth. Argentina's growth is impressive, some 10%, but
unless it clears its foreign debt hurdle there is no guarantee that the recent
performance will continue over the medium term. Russia and a few transition
economies also show strong growth, although, as in the case of many Latin
America countries, the boom in raw materials and energy prices has significantly
contributed to this outcome. To a large extent, this world recovery is due to
the strength of the Asian economies, which have overcome the trauma of the
crisis in 1997-98 and are now growing again at rates around 6-7 percent. It is
not only the Asian dragons and China (the latter leading with a rate of growth
of slightly above 10% annually), but particular mention should also go to India,
which is now reaping the benefits of the liberalization it introduced after the
mid-1990s and is now growing at 7%, a rate more than double its customary 3
percent. It should be recalled that the US is also growing rapidly and its
import demand has continued to be a source of growth for the world economy.
Whereas some 10 years ago the E.U. was the main beneficiary of dynamic US demand,
nowadays the center of gravity has moved to the Pacific rim. This is reflected
in a rate of growth of world trade in the Pacific rim estimated at about 11% on
average in 2003/2004, which is more than three times the corresponding rate of
growth of the overseas trade of the EU. In 2003 more than one quarter of the
increase in world trade was due to China, whose international trade grew at
almost 40% last year. The east Asian tigers (Korea, Taiwan, Thailand, Malaysia)
have been dwarfed by a Colossus which, however, has the vitality of a tiger.
Én order to better gauge the growing role of China in the world economy,
assuming that its high growth rate continues, we can calculate that the annual
increment of its GDP in the years to come is as if a country of almost the size
of Spain (the 9th biggest market economy worldwide) was being integrated into
the world economy every year.
Accelerating growth is taking place in a non-inflationary
climate, with price increases remaining at or below 2 percent in the developed
world and in many emerging economies. We can now take comfort that we have, at
least temporarily, tamed the beast of inflation that bedeviled our economies in
the 1970s and 1980s, while the fears of deflationary pressures that were
widespread last summer have certainly not materialized. These improvements are
partly due to improved macroeconomic policies, but they also reflect fundamental
changes as a result of new technologies, as well as a more competitive and pro-business
climate all over the world. The rapidly growing share of world exports
originating from the low labor cost countries (China, India and others) is also
exerting a downward pressure on prices globally. The much-maligned dotcom bubble
did reflect an improvement in technological possibilities, which we are now
observing as increasing productivity in many countries. It is not for nothing
that much of the global investment revival now comes from the technology sector.
Within this overall booming environment, it is slightly
distressing that the core economies of the eurozone remain the laggards.
Although all European economies have now emerged from recession, the three main
economies, Germany, France and Italy, will see very modest growth of less than 1
½ percent in total this year. Certainly, this slow growth cannot be blamed on
macroeconomic factors, which remain conducive to growth. The external
environment is improving fast, monetary policy, as conducted by the ECB, remains
supportive of growth, and fiscal policy, as reflected in an overall fiscal
deficit in the eurozone of close to 3 percent, is expansionary. Even the euro's
appreciation has been halted and wage growth remains moderate at 2 ?% annually.
While it is easy to eliminate macroeconomic policy as the cause of slow growth
in the eurozone, it is much more difficult to pinpoint the culprits of this
sluggish recovery.
Maybe there is no single cause, and the situation differs
from country to country. Some eurozone members, like Italy, have difficulty
adapting to a situation where the nominal exchange rate is appreciating and the
country faces growing competition from low-cost producers in many of its
traditional industrial sectors (textiles, shoe making, garments etc.). Prior to
Eurozone membership, many, especially in the business sector, had taken it for
granted that the exchange rate only depreciates. In other countries, the
uncertainties induced by the stubbornly high unemployment rate and the slow
progress in structural changes are depressing economic sentiment and are holding
back consumption and investment, despite the marked improvements in corporate
profitability across sectors in 2003 & 2004. I do not think that the
Eurozone is facing the fundamental problems that Japan faced over the last ten
years. It is more the confluence of many factors that exert a negative influence
on our economies. Pessimism is one of them and has permeated many economic
circles and is in itself a worrying phenomenon. This is reflected in the fact
that the recent recovery, instead of being compared to stronger previous
cyclical recoveries, is compared to the worst phases of the cycle - the
declining output towards the end of 2002 and the first half of 2003. In the same
vein, a very low potential rate of growth of barely above 2% per year for the
Euroarea is considered by many as a normal benchmark against which outcomes are
measured. Therefore, a 0,5% shortfall, i.e. a rate of growth in the Euroarea of
about 1.5% as is projected for 2004, is implicitly considered broadly
satisfactory, despite the fact that there is still a negative output gap. Given
the interaction between actual GDP growth and potential growth, a sharper
rebound of the Euroarea, as was the case in cyclical upturns in the past, would
by itself have raised the rate of growth of potential GDP. Indeed, if assisted
by bold structural reforms the rate of growth of potential in the Euroarea could
be raised to over 2.5%, the same rate as in the 1980s and a rate more normal for
mature economies. The potential rate of growth of the US has averaged just over
3% over the last twenty five years. If too much pessimism regarding the
potential rate of growth dampens actual growth and, therefore, may to some
extent be self-fulfilling, equally dangerous is over-optimism, or better (to use
the famous words) irrational exuberance, that is quickly disproven. What is
needed is a sober assessment of the situation and the introduction urgently of
appropriate structural reforms, so that not only macro - but also micro -
economic policies are geared to supporting a stronger non-inflationary growth
than today.
Though the cause of to-day's ills in the Euroarea are
essentially of domestic origin, I hinted earlier that exchange rate policies
followed by certain heavy weights in international trade have resulted in a real
effective appreciation of the euro more than is warranted and, moreover, it
seems that from a dynamic point of view the appreciation is much greater than
the published figures show, which are necessarily based on past data. As a
result, whereas the Euroarea, one of the richest regions of the globe should
have had a sizeable current account surplus so as to fulfill its natural world
role as a sizeable capital exporter (a surplus would also be expected because of
its weak cyclical phase), the current account surplus of the Euroarea has
averaged only $17 billion annually since 2000, compared to $26 billion for China
and $ 80 billion for the dragons, whose per capita income is still relatively
low. Of course, if Euroarea growth was faster, this aspect would not be so
important since more market determined exchange rates in these countries would
probably only add not more than one quarter of a percentage point to Euroarea
growth. However, with average growth in the Euroarea of less than 0.7% in
2002/2003, even a small stimulus matters.
In this context I would like to say something about the Greek
economy itself. Unlike our partners in the EU, we are now enjoying strong growth
that will stay close to 4 percent this year as in the last five years.
Admittedly, the stimulus from the forthcoming Olympic Games and the inflow of EU
structural funds has contributed to the good economic performance; but I think
it is true to say that endogenous factors have been significantly more important.
Public expenditure on the Olympic Games, amounting to just over 1% of GDP in the
last few years, has also had the negative effect of raising the fiscal deficit
to about its upper limit of 3%, set by the European Treaty, and has also
intensified inflationary expectations. As a result external competitiveness will
again probably be eroded somewhat in 2004, in turn restraining GDP growth. As
for financial support from the E.U., it is worth mentioning that net inflows
from the E.U. have fallen from over 5% of GDP at the end of 1990s to 2.8% in
2003. The Greek economy has succeeded in absorbing this negative shock without
strains and the probable further decline in net E.U. funds, after 2007, which is
related to E.U. enlargement, does not pose a serious threat to growth. Against
these negative influences there is an array of positive factors, starting from
the fundamental changes in the economy that have occurred in the last fifteen
years and are easily visible to the naked eye. Not only is the economy
functioning more efficiently, and reflecting a high investment-to-GDP ratio of
26%, the capital base both in the private and public sector has broadened and
deepened, but also business initiative is on the rise, and the factors in
combination with the removal of exchange rate risk and low interest rates
creates a more stable environment and helps promote both consumption and private
investment. Greece, being close to the fast-growing economies of Eastern Europe
and the Balkan area, benefits from its ever-improving economic links with them
and is becoming a hub for many of them. We are also seeing the first fruits of
the heavy infrastructure investment and structural reforms we undertook in
recent years, which underpin a relatively fast rate of underlying productivity
growth, at almost 3%, or nearly three times that of the Euroarea. While some
deceleration of growth immediately and for a short period after the Olympics may
occur, I remain confident that Greece will stay on a dynamic growth path for
years to come provided that fiscal consolidation accelerates and bureaucratic
blockages are eliminated.
While one can be fairly confident about the world economy's
prospects for 2004, I have already hinted that challenges may emerge in 2005 and
beyond. Real GDP growth is not expected to accelerate in 2005, while the
downside risks loom larger. These challenges are a bit further down the road,
but in a fast-moving world prevarication is not a good strategy and I shall
mention the most important:
Certainly, the largest threat looming over the world economy
in the medium-to-longer term is the "twin deficits" in the US. The
fiscal deficit is the most worrying and despite plans for a drastic cut over the
next few years, it may be difficult to achieve it in the light of the U.S.
involvements worldwide, the likely increase in the interest rate on Treasury
Bills, and a projected slowdown of economic growth from the high rate of 4.7%
estimated for 2004. Only ambitious measures could make a significant dent in the
fiscal deficit and this is needed both for the US and for the stability of the
world economy.
A decline of the fiscal deficit will by itself reduce
somewhat the current account deficit. But, given the asymmetry between the high
income elasticity of demand for imports in the US of over 2 and the low foreign
income elasticity for US exports only of 1, only a partial correction is
possible. Elimination of the current account deficit cannot, therefore, be
envisaged under present conditions and, moreover, it is not needed. Given the
safe heaven status and high profitability in the US, financing the balance of
payments deficit is less of a problem. Indeed the fears that the deficit would
trigger further rapid depreciation of the US dollar, equal to that seen in the
last two years, have not materialized and most likely will not materialize. The
world is finally getting accustomed to the idea that a structural deficit of
around 3% of GDP over the medium term can be sustained, and this should be the
goal.
The rise in the price of oil close to $40 per barrel is a
serious threat to the world economic recovery and needs to be urgently addressed.
If maintained, such a high price could impact negatively to the tune of 0.5% of
GDP over the next eighteen months and will exacerbate inflationary pressures.
Fast rising world demand, especially in China with its low energy and raw-material
efficiency (as in the case for energy in the US), is an important factor behind
the steep rise of oil and particularly of raw and intermediate material prices.
On the supply side, the policy of some big oil producing countries, which have
subordinated the goal of a stable international environment conducive to
sustainable growth world-wide to their short-run need for revenues to cover
fiscal deficits, is also contributing to the maintenance of high oil prices.
Political factors may have also played role in the changing attitude of some
producers. The rise in oil and raw material prices is accentuating inflationary
pressures and may lead to a premature monetary policy tightening in many
countries, especially if these pressures are allowed to spill over to wages.
Such a move would definitely lead to even slower growth than the mechanical
impact of the rise in the oil price would suggest. Especially in the US, which
has followed an expansionary monetary policy in the last few years, a rise in
interest rates may have a strong cumulative impact on growth. Though such a
development would help reduce the current account deficit it will certainly make
fiscal consolidation in the US even more difficult.
Last, but not least, Chinese growth may slow, but this is a
welcome development since recent very strong growth was exacerbating
disequilibria in China and world-wide. The authorities seem to have realized
that growth close to 10- 12%, as recorded in the last few quarters, intensifies
inflationary pressures and encourages investments in uneconomical projects,
which have no chance to service their debt. The official inflation rate of 3% is
being questioned in financial circles, which estimate that actual inflation is
closer to 6% and if we include real estate and asset prices, inflation probably
is even higher. Recently, the central bank tightened monetary conditions and
introduced credit restrictions and the authorities ordered the postponement and
even cancellation of many projects not only in order to prevent overheating but
also in order to encourage banks to clear their non-performing portfolio and
increase their capital base. The authorities seem also to be considering an
appreciation of the renminbi, though not immediately, which would ease inflation
and contribute to a better management of their financial resources. We have to
see whether these measures will contribute to a soft-landing, thus allowing
China to avoid the bitter experience of some of its neighbors in 1997-1998, when
their credit and asset inflation bubble burst. The rate of growth of potential
output in China is estimated at around 7% per annum, which is still high, and
thus China will continue to be a dynamic player in the world economy, while at
the same time help to stem the rising disequilibria world wide.